Notes navigation: Browse by title • Browse by author • Subject index
Disclaimer. Don't rely on these old notes in lieu of reading the literature, but they can jog your memory. As a grad student long ago, my peers and I collaborated to write and exchange summaries of political science research. I posted them to a wiki-style website. "Wikisum" is now dead but archived here. I cannot vouch for these notes' accuracy, nor can I say who wrote them.
Milgrom, North, and Weingast. 1990. The role of institutions in the revival of trade: The medieval law merchant, private judges, and [...]. Economics and Politics 1: 1-23.
In medieval times, how could one merchant trust other merchants to deal honestly?
The Law Merchant system was a private code of laws among merchants, with disputes adjudicated by a local official or a private merchant, that became widespread by end of 11th century. These judges had no police power and could not enforce judgments, nor was there a state to do so. Yet somehow this system was sufficient to make trade possible. This article seeks to explain why.
Without institutions like the Law Merchant system, any interaction between two merchants would be a prisoner's dilemma. Each merchant has strong incentives to cheat the other.
This tit-for-tat equilibrium can also be reached even among constantly changing opponents if all the opponents (i.e. merchants) belong to a common community. Tit-for-tat becomes adjusted tit-for-tat (ATFT): If you cheat a merchant, you will be punished by the next merchant you deal with, even if he wasn't the one you cheated.
ATFT works for two reasons:
Of course, this model assumes everyones knows what happens in each trade. This assumption is plausible within a small community of merchants using the reputation system.
ATFT wasn't enough to make trade possible among medieval merchants, though. They belonged to a large, dispersed community of merchants, so even if they wanted to use the ATFT strategy, it would be difficult to know whom to punish.
To play ATFT, merchants had two problems to solve.
The Law Merchant (LM) institution solved this problems. The Law Merchant could
Seen as a formal game, this is the sequence of play:
As it usually worked out, traders would only query the LM in advance if they themselves had no unpaid judgments. Usually, the payoff from honest behavior would be 1 - Q (where 1 is the payoff of honesty, Q is transaction cost of query, 0 is payoff from not trading at all, and the cost of being cheated is negative)
The LM has an incentive to remain honest to protect his income flow from merchants who trust him. Merchants would be unwilling to pay him for future queries and judgments if word got out that he were corrupt.
LM's make reputation system work better. Queries allow you to know one's reputation (or at least enough of it). Unpaid judgments hurt your reputation. Paying judgments costs more than being honest in the first place. So merchants should be honest.
Related ideas you may encounter: Public stocks, the "scarlet letter," and similar mechanisms also were used to tell you who has violated the community norms.
Should we really believe that the LM has incentives not to take bribes? While it may be true that each trader "expects that if he pays a bribe he will be subjected to repeated attempts at extortion in the future," isn't it also true that each trader fears the costs of being the only trader not paying the bribe? It seems that this is another prisoner's dilemma.
Research by the same authors
Research on similar subjects
Tags
Milgrom, Paul (author) • North, Douglass (author) • Weingast, Barry (author) • Economics • Information • Trade • Prisoner's Dilemma • Credible Commitment • Institutions • Origins of Institutions • Incentives in Market Exchange
Wikisum home: Index of all summaries by title, by author, or by subject.